digplanet beta 1: Athena
Share digplanet:

Agriculture

Applied sciences

Arts

Belief

Business

Chronology

Culture

Education

Environment

Geography

Health

History

Humanities

Language

Law

Life

Mathematics

Nature

People

Politics

Science

Society

Technology

The Slutsky equation (or Slutsky identity) in economics, named after Eugen Slutsky (1880–1948), relates changes in Marshallian (uncompensated) demand to changes in Hicksian (compensated) demand, which is known as such since it compensates to maintain a fixed level of utility. The equation demonstrates that the change in the demand for a good, caused by a price change, is the result of two effects:

The Slutsky equation decomposes the change in demand for good i in response to a change in the price of good j:

{\partial x_i(\mathbf{p}, w) \over \partial p_j} = {\partial h_i(\mathbf{p}, u) \over \partial p_j} - {\partial x_i(\mathbf{p}, w) \over \partial w } x_j(\mathbf{p}, w),\,

where h(\mathbf{p}, u) is the Hicksian demand and x(\mathbf{p}, w) is the Marshallian demand, at the vector of price levels \mathbf{p}, wealth level (or, alternatively, income level) w, and fixed utility level u given by maximizing utility at the original price and income, formally given by the indirect utility function v(\mathbf{p}, w). The right-hand side of the equation is equal to the change in demand for good i holding utility fixed at u minus the quantity of good j demanded, multiplied by the change in demand for good i when wealth changes.

The first term on the right-hand side represents the substitution effect, and the second term represents the income effect.[1] Note that since utility is not observable, the substitution effect is not directly observable, but it can be calculated by reference to the other two terms in the Slutsky equation, which are observable. This process is sometimes known as the Hicks decomposition of a demand change.[2]

The same equation can be rewritten in matrix form to allow multiple price changes at once:

\mathbf{D_p x}(\mathbf{p}, w) = \mathbf{D_p h}(\mathbf{p}, u)- \mathbf{D_w x}(\mathbf{p}, w) \mathbf{x}(\mathbf{p}, w)^\top,\,

where Dp is the derivative operator with respect to price and Dw is the derivative operator with respect to wealth.

The matrix \mathbf{D_p h}(\mathbf{p}, u) is known as the Slutsky matrix, and given sufficient smoothness conditions on the utility function, it is symmetric, negative semidefinite, and the Hessian of the expenditure function.

Derivation[edit]

While there are several ways to derive the Slutsky equation, the following method is likely the simplest. Begin by noting the identity h_i(\mathbf{p},u) = x_i (\mathbf{p}, e(\mathbf{p},u)) where  e(\mathbf{p},u) is the expenditure function, and u is the utility obtained by maximizing utility given p and w. Totally differentiating with respect to pj yields the following:

 \frac{\partial h_i(\mathbf{p},u)}{\partial p_j} = \frac{\partial x_i(\mathbf{p},e(\mathbf{p},u))}{\partial p_j}  + \frac{\partial x_i (\mathbf{p},e(\mathbf{p},u))}{\partial e(\mathbf{p},u)} \cdot \frac{\partial e(\mathbf{p},u)}{\partial p_j}.

Making use of the fact that  \frac{\partial e(\mathbf{p},u)}{\partial p_j} = h_j(\mathbf{p},u) by Shephard's lemma and that at optimum,

 h_j(\mathbf{p},u) = h_j(\mathbf{p}, v(\mathbf{p},w)) = x_j(\mathbf{p},w), where v(\mathbf{p},w) is the indirect utility function,

one can substitute and rewrite the derivation above as the Slutsky equation.

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^ Nicholson, W. (2005). Microeconomic Theory (10th ed.). Mason, Ohio: Thomson Higher Education. 
  2. ^ Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (3rd ed.). New York: W. W. Norton. 

Original courtesy of Wikipedia: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Slutsky_equation — Please support Wikipedia.
This page uses Creative Commons Licensed content from Wikipedia. A portion of the proceeds from advertising on Digplanet goes to supporting Wikipedia.
2633 videos foundNext > 

11a. The Slutsky Equation and Demand Curves

In this video, I offer a derivation of the Slutsky Equation (an equation that decomposes the Marshallian demand curve's price effect into income and substitu...

slutsky hicks.mov

Brian O'Roark from Robert Morris University illustrates the income and substitution effects through the Slutsky and Hicks approaches.

Income and Substitution Effects

The spreadsheet for this video is the 4th one in the workbook you can download here. http://goo.gl/dbR89 The standard Slutsky decomposition of the effect of ...

Slutsky equation of labour supply

Income and Substitution Effects (Mathematically)

Chapter - Income and Substitution Effects (Mathematically) This microeconomics series by EurekaWow is aligned with the textbook Hal Varian (baby version) as ...

Income and Substitution Effects: Price Decrease

If you already know how to maximize utility, this video shows you how to find income and substitution effects using "Hicks Decomposition": New Prices/Old Uti...

6 Hicksian and Slutsky Substitution and Income Effect

6 Micro-econ.

Aula sobre Legalização de drogas, Preferências e Equação de Slutsky

Aula pretende abordar o que aconteceria no Brasil com a legalização das drogas. Será que legalizando as drogas haverá uma redução da criminalidade relacionad...

50 Cesar & Os Economistas - Slutsky Violento

Trabalho de microeconomia 3 sobre a equação de slutsky. Nome dos integrantes Gabriel Soares Bernardo Bedran Julio Cesar Rafael Fernandes Lucas Rezende Ibmec ...

Microeconomía I - Tema 5. Ejercicio 2 - Alfonso Rosa

http://www.ucam.edu/estudios/grados/ade-semipresencial Departamento: Facultad de Ciencias Jurídicas y Empresariales Titulación: Grado en Administración y Dir...

2633 videos foundNext > 

We're sorry, but there's no news about "Slutsky equation" right now.

Loading

Oops, we seem to be having trouble contacting Twitter

Support Wikipedia

A portion of the proceeds from advertising on Digplanet goes to supporting Wikipedia. Please add your support for Wikipedia!